This is the second installment of the word match challenge that I introduced in 7 Deadly Sins of the Government Debt Debate – #1. The idea is to match the seven “sins” in the right-hand column below to the seven topics on the left. In this article, I’ll ask if you agree with my answer for topic #2: “Unexpected Events.” But before I give you that answer, I’ll share new research showing that the current debate on debt reduction fails to consider one of the biggest impediments that we face.
Unexpected events
Alongside its long-term budget forecasts, the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) offers the advice to expect the unexpected. It warns of unfortunate events that occur with some regularity, even though their timing isn’t known in advance. Here’s my record of the CBO’s concerns:
The CBO wants us to know that these risks aren’t reflected in its debt projections. And it’s right to warn us of the many ways that its projections could be knocked off track. But the projections are numeric and tangible, while the warnings are vague and intangible. And no matter how many times they’re repeated, they’re still vague and intangible. Let’s see if we can make them more real. My approach won’t be perfect but it’s easier than you may think. I’ve looked back three decades and simply added up the government’s unexpected spending, considering most of the setbacks listed in the table above. Here’s the data that I used (with links to the original sources included at the end of the article):
- The net supplemental spending costs in the 89 laws enacted between 1981 and 2010 that contained either supplemental appropriations or rescissions (cancellations of prior appropriations). Supplemental appropriations provide additional funding outside the normal budgeting process, allowing Congress to respond to unanticipated needs or priorities. Examples from the last three decades include the first Gulf War, the Iraq and Afghan Wars (until Obama added their costs to the annual appropriation process in 2010), a slew of natural disasters, a few terrorist attacks and various other types of unexpected spending.
- The estimated effects of automatic stabilizers on the government’s annual budget balances. Automatic stabilizers are counter-cyclical changes in government finances triggered purely by the economy’s movement through the business cycle. They don’t include the costs of proactive stimulus measures. In other words, they represent the natural fiscal costs of recessions (and benefits of expansions).
- The estimated costs of three stimulus packages intended to either forestall or lessen the effects of recessions: the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act (ARRA) of 2009, the Economic Stimulus Act of 2008, and a relatively small stimulus package that Bush 43 signed in 2002. Other forms of stimulus are ignored because they weren’t wholly temporary responses to recessions (for example, Reagan’s 1981 tax cuts and Bush’s 2001 tax cuts), or they were counted in supplemental appropriations that I had already considered.
- The estimated costs of the savings and loan industry bailout[1] and the Fannie Mae and Freddy Mac bailouts.[2] Smaller bailouts and those that were mostly reimbursed are ignored. TARP is the most notable omission, especially as there are many reasons to distrust the government’s published figures for this program.[3] But calculating its true costs would have required the kind of complex assumptions that I’m trying to avoid.
I calculated that unexpected events cost the government 1.1% of GDP per year for the period 1981 to 2010. Here’s the breakdown:
The next step is to ask the question: Is my historical estimate a reasonable benchmark for the future costs of unexpected events? I say yes, and the future could be worse. My answer is based partly on economic trends that I’ll discuss in the next article in this series. And it’s also based on the observation that things weren’t so bad in the last three decades. The economy was strong most of the time, such that automatic stabilizers actually reduced the deficit in ten years out of thirty. Only one recession – the big one from 2008 to mid-2009 – led to stimulus and bailout measures that were both significant and qualified for inclusion in my calculations. Until that recession, the economy had been so stable that the time period came to be known as the Great Moderation. Moreover, it doesn’t include any of the four most expensive wars of the last 100 years: World War I, World War II, Korea and Vietnam. And my estimate excludes delayed costs of the wars that did occur, such as the veterans expenses that often exceed the initial costs of fighting a war.
In my opinion, debt projections should include allowances for budget slippage of at least 1% of GDP. If you’re a perpetual optimist and prefer to think that budget plans never go off track, I suggest at least conducting a suitable stress test for unexpected spending. Call it a “high spending” scenario to leave room for a more hopeful base case. (This should be agreeable to all but those disconnected from economic reality, such as economists.)
To give some meaning to an allowance for budget slippage, I’ll compare the risk of unexpected spending to the current debate on long-term debt reduction. In the top panel of the table below, I’ve converted the cost figures shown above from GDP percentages to dollar amounts. In the bottom panel, I’ve included various CBO estimates for the deficit reduction associated with certain policy changes. And in both cases, I’m showing amounts for the year 2020 to be consistent with the CBO publication I used as a guide (again, see data links at the end of the article).
If you’re familiar with today’s political debates, you know the deficit reduction measures in the table are all controversial. And that it would take tremendous compromises to enact just a few of them. As of this writing, only half of one measure has been implemented (Obama’s threshold for rich people was still $250,000 when the CBO published these estimates, before the compromise agreement raising it to $450,000). What’s less understood is that the deficit reduction from just a few measures would be offset by a simple repeat of the typical budgetary surprises of the last 30 years.
I’ll say it again differently: Once you recognize the inevitable budget slippage, it’s hard to imagine today’s cast of characters coming up with a debt reduction plan that even gets them back to where they started. I won’t call budget slippage the elephant in the room, since this particular room is full of elephants. Let’s just say it’s the elephant crap that gets swept under the carpet. (If you’ve never seen an elephant crap, you should add this to your bucket list – definitely my all-time, most memorable zoo experience.)
Again, my approach to measuring the problem is imperfect. A team of experts could do a better job estimating the future costs of unexpected events. The CBO’s modelers could do a better job blending the estimates into their projections. But these steps aren’t included in projections because many events are deemed too unpredictable to be estimated – an excuse that defies both collective knowledge and common practice. Actuaries, accountants and financial risk managers are all trained to place numerical estimates on unforeseen risks. Insurance premiums, credit loss provisions and investment decisions are all based on these numerical estimates.
The key is that any positive number is better than nothing. We can see the problem with nothing just by noticing that the debt debate almost never gets around to the risks of recessions, financial crises, wars, natural disasters, and so on. Political leaders and pundits habitually ignore the CBO’s warnings that these events will occur from time to time, relying instead on its incomplete projections. And for the omissions in these projections, I’ll match topic #2 to neglect.
Check back on Monday to see who I think should be the Fed Chairman. And on Wednesday for the next word match topic – Pension Fund Accounting.
Data links
Supplemental appropriations
- Congressional Budget Office, “Supplemental Appropriations in the 1980s,” Congressional Budget Office Publication #512, February 1990, http://www.cbo.gov/publication/17127.
- Congressional Budget Office, “Supplemental Appropriations in the 1990s,” March 2001, http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/ftpdocs/27xx/doc2768/entirereport.pdf.
- Congressional Budget Office, “CBO Data on Supplemental Budget Authority for the 2000’s,” http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/ftpdocs/66xx/doc6630/suppapprops.pdf.
- Thomas L. Hungerford, “Supplemental Appropriations: Trends and Budgetary Impacts Since 1981,” Congressional Research Service Report RL33134, January 2, 2009, http://assets.opencrs.com/rpts/RL33134_20090102.pdf (Wikileaks Document Release, http://wikileaks.org/wiki/CRS-RL33134, February 2, 2009).
Automatic stabilizers
- Congressional Budget Office, “Introduction to Quarterly Estimates of the Federal Budget Deficit or Surplus With and Without Automatic Stabilizers,” May 2010, http://www.cbo.gov/publication/42323.
Bailouts
- Timothy Curry and Lynn Shabut, “The Cost of the Savings and Loan Crisis: Truth and Consequences,” FDIC Banking Review 13 (2000), No. 2, 26-35, http://www.fdic.gov/bank/analytical/banking/2000dec/brv13n2_2.pdf.
- United States Department of the Treasury, “2010 Financial Report of the United States Government,” vii, http://www.fms.treas.gov/fr/10frusg/10frusg.pdf.
Proactive fiscal stimulus
- Congressional Budget Office, “H.R. 5140: Economic Stimulus Act of 2008,” Congressional Budget Office Cost Estimate, February 11, 2008, http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/ftpdocs/89xx/doc8973/hr5140pgo.pdf.
- Congressional Budget Office, “H.R. 3890: Job Creation and Worker Assistance Act of 2002,” Congressional Budget Office Pay-as-you-go Cost Estimate, May 3, 2002, http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/ftpdocs/34xx/doc3416/hr3090.pdf.
- Update to “Summary of the Estimated Cost of the Conference Agreement for H.R. 1, the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009,” Congressional Budget Office, February 13, 2009.
Effects of deficit reduction measures
- Congressional Budget Office, “An Update to the Budget and Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 2012 to 2022,” August 2012, http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/attachments/08-22-2012-Update_to_Outlook.pdf.
- Congressional Budget Office, “Letter to the Honorable John Boehner Providing an Estimate for H.R. 6079, The Repeal of Obamacare Act,” July 24, 2012, http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/attachments/43471-hr6079.pdf.
- Congressional Budget Office, “Choices for Deficit Reduction,” November 2012, http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/attachments/43692-DeficitReduction_print.pdf.
[1] I assigned these costs to 1991 to keep it simple even though the costs were spread over a longer period from 1986 to 1995.
[2] Including only the payments made through the end of the 2010 fiscal year.
[3] See, for example, Bailout: An Inside Account of How Washington Abandoned Main Street While Rescuing Wall Street, by Neil Barofsky, the former Special Inspector General for TARP. Or, for a short and typically entertaining article from Matt Taibbi, see “Secrets and Lies of the Bailout” from the January 17, 2013 issue of Rolling Stone.
Pingback: The 8% Solution | CYNICOMOMICS
Pingback: Seven Deadly Sins of the Government Debt Debate – #4 | CYNICOMOMICS
Pingback: The Debt Paradox That Everyone Should Be Aware Of | CYNICOMOMICS
Pingback: One Blogger’s Word Association for Crony Capitalism | CYNICOMOMICS